When to Rob a Bank: ...And 131 More Warped Suggestions and Well-Intended Rants (9 page)

BOOK: When to Rob a Bank: ...And 131 More Warped Suggestions and Well-Intended Rants
8.12Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

(Hat tip to
John List
, the only baseball-memorabilia-salesman-turned-economist I know.)

If Only God Had Had Corporate Sponsorship . . .
(SJD)

. . . in the book of Genesis, when the world is created. Can you imagine how rich He could have gotten by selling the naming rights of every animal, mineral, and vegetable?

If God was unlucky to toil in the days before corporate sponsorship, the Chicago White Sox are not so unlucky. They have
just announced
that for the next three seasons, their evening home games will begin at 7:11
P.M
. instead of the customary 7:05
P.M.
or 7:35
P.M.
Why? Because 7-Eleven, the convenience store chain, is paying them $500,000 to do so.

I’ve lately noticed advertisements showing up in a lot of unlikely venues: stamped onto fresh eggs and printed on airplane barf bags, for instance. But I have to admit there is something particularly creative about affixing a value to time itself, especially if you can capture that value for your own benefit.

Maybe I will write more about that tomorrow™.

What Captain Sullenberger Meant to Say (But Was Too Polite to Do So)
(BY “CAPTAIN STEVE”)

Captain Steve is a seasoned international pilot for a major U.S. carrier and a friend of Freakonomics. (Given the sensitivity of what he writes, he prefers anonymity.) This post was published on June 24, 2009, six months after the “The Miracle on the Hudson,” in which Captain Chesley Sullenberger safely landed an Airbus A320-200 in the Hudson River. Both the plane’s engines had failed, due to a bird strike, shortly after takeoff from LaGuardia Airport in New York.

After reading some of the excerpts of Captain Sullenberger’s various speeches, especially those of a few weeks ago with the National Transportation Safety Board, I would like to add my editorial.

Captain Sullenberger has been a class act all the way. He’s not been petty, pious, or egotistical. He is, however, like most of the captains I know and, more broadly, most of the pilots I know. Why? He doesn’t need to be otherwise. When someone has accomplished what he and the scores of men and women like him have accomplished, why do we need to boast?

He implies that what he did while serving as the “skipper” of US Airways flight 1549 was simply his job. He is being as honest and accurate as he can be: “Please, no fanfare, no applause, just doing my job.” But what he has also
alluded to in some of his speeches is that it has taken years, even decades, to prepare himself for that one single “lifetime event” of guiding his jet into the safe, smooth landing on the Hudson River.

What he is not saying is this:

We, the airline pilots, are facing a losing battle in the PR department. You believe that we make huge salaries and are treated like royalty. Pure fiction. Why have we been losing this battle for such a long time? Simple. Because most of us are like “Sully”; we don’t want applause or fanfare for doing what we are trained to do. However, we do realize that we should be fairly compensated for what we have achieved to get this job and what we continue to do on a daily basis to keep it. This backlash of pilot-bashing is building to a boiling point.

Regional carriers, like the
Colgan Airlines flight in Buffalo
[which crashed, killing all forty-nine aboard], employ the lowest-bidder pilots. No offense to them; this is not personal. It is the system that is at fault. Money and profits at all cost.

Airline history lesson 101: it used to be, up until the mid 1980s, that a young pilot would be hired on at a major carrier, become a flight engineer (FE), and then spend a few years managing the systems of the older-generation airplanes. But he or she was learning all the while. These new “pilots” sat in the FE seat and did their job, all the while observing the “pilots” doing the flying, day in and day out.

The FEs learned from the seasoned pilots about the
real world of flying into the O’Hares and LaGuardias. They learned decision making, delegation, and the reality of “captain’s final authority” as confirmed in the law. When they got the chance to upgrade, they became a copilot. The copilot’s duty was to assist the captain in flying; but even during their time as the new copilot, they had the luxury of the FE looking over their shoulders—i.e., more learning. This three-man-crew concept, now a fond memory in the domestic markets but used predominately in international flying, was considered one more layer of protection.

But it’s gone. Now domestic flying is being shifted to the regional carriers, like Colgan, American Eagle, Comair, and Mesa, to name a few. These consist of the lowest bidders and the newest pilots flying into the harshest of environments. The airline management teams would say that it works and that this is routine flying. I beg to differ.

Analogy: you are told you need a quadruple bypass. Now you search the Internet for the cheapest price you can get, and you rush to schedule the operation because there are only two dates that you can get that cheap rate.

Do any of us do that? No. What do we do? We get second opinions, we ask who is the best in town, etc. We ask: “Is there anyone who has been doing this surgery for the last twenty to twenty-five years?” We don’t say, “Let me use someone who just graduated from medical school and was rushed through residency because it will be cheaper.”

Why not apply the same logic that the public uses to buy
an airplane ticket to this surgery scenario? Bypass surgery is routine, right? Some surgeons do two, three, or four a day. It must be easy.

To take that a step further, how many surgeons have to retake their medical boards every nine months in order to be qualified? Airline pilots do. We are subject to simulator check-rides every nine months to demonstrate knowledge, proficiency, and ability.

How many surgeons have to take a physical exam every six months by the AMA in order to work? None! Airline pilots do. Fail your medical exam and you’re done! How many surgeons (or any other critical professional, including politicians) are subject to random drug and alcohol testing? None.

Flying across the North Atlantic is routine, right? It wasn’t just a short few decades ago. We, the pilots, make it routine because we have skills, experience, and training like very few others.

Gifted? No, not many of us are. But dedicated and focused upon excellence, you bet! I have told my kids one thing many times since they were little children: “I don’t expect perfection, I expect excellence.” I expect 100 percent effort in all you do. This is the creed of every pilot I know.

Flying from Chicago’s O’Hare to Denver is routine, right? We, the pilots, make it so. But is your life worth less over the heartland of America rather than over the Atlantic? It certainly is if you are on the low-cost regional carrier. If you
are on such a plane headed to Denver and the engine is on fire, I am sure it is comforting to know that you saved 15 percent by scouring the Internet for the cheapest fare. Isn’t it great to know that you have the newest, least-experienced, exhausted, starving young cockpit crew that this regional airline could find?

Did I say starving? Yeah, I did. Did you know that these regional crews can work for twelve to thirteen hours every day, flying five to eight legs a day, but their airline does not feel it’s important enough to provide food for them? They are already on welfare wages, and now they have to find time and money while on the ground for twenty-five minutes to simply nourish themselves. It’s a sad state of affairs. Remember, you bought the cheapest ticket.

Hurray For High Gas Prices!
(SDL)

This post was published in June 2007, when the average price of regular gasoline in the U.S. was $2.80 per gallon, having risen dramatically in previous months. A year later, the price would hit $4. As of this writing (January 2015), the price has fallen all the way to $2.06 per gallon. So even without adjusting for inflation, gas is 26 percent cheaper now than when this post was written. The federal gas tax, meanwhile, hasn’t been raised since 1993.

For a long time I have felt the price of gasoline in the United States was way too low. Pretty much all economists believe this, and also believe therefore that the gas tax should be raised substantially.

The reason we need high gas taxes is that there are all sorts of costs associated with my driving that I don’t pay—someone else pays them. This is what economists call a “negative externality.” Because I don’t pay the full costs of my driving, I drive too much. Ideally, the government could correct this problem through a gas tax that aligns my own private incentive to drive with the social costs of driving.

Three possible externalities associated with driving are the following:

        
a.
My driving increases congestion for other drivers.

        
b.
I might crash into other cars or pedestrians.

        
c.
My driving contributes to global warming.

If you had to guess, which of those three considerations provides the strongest justification for a bigger tax on gasoline?

The answer, at least based on the evidence I could find, may surprise you.

The most obvious one is congestion. Traffic jams are a direct consequence of too many cars on the road. If you took some cars away, the remaining drivers could get places much faster. From
Wikipedia’s page on traffic congestion
:

The
Texas Transportation Institute
estimates that in 2000 the 75 largest metropolitan areas experienced 3.6 billion vehicle-hours of delay, resulting in 5.7 billion US gallons (21.6 billion liters) in wasted fuel and $67.5 billion in lost productivity, or about 0.7% of the nation’s
GDP
.

This particular study doesn’t tell us what we really need to know for estimating how big the gas tax should be. (We want to know how much adding one driver to the mix affects lost productivity.) But it does get to the point that, as a commuter, I’m better off if you decide to call in sick today.

A more subtle benefit of having fewer drivers is that there would be fewer crashes. Aaron Edlin and Pinar Mandic, in a
paper I was proud to publish
in the
Journal of Political Economy,
argue convincingly that each extra driver raises the insurance costs of other drivers by about $2,000. Their key point is that if my car is not there to crash into, maybe a crash never happens. They conclude that the appropriate tax would generate $220 billion annually. So, if they are right, reducing the number of crashes is a more important justification for a gas tax than reducing congestion. I’m not sure I believe this; it certainly is a result I never would have guessed to be true.

How about global warming? Every gallon of gas I burn releases carbon into the atmosphere, presumably speeding global warming. If you can believe
Wikipedia’s entry on the
carbon tax
, the social cost of a ton of carbon put into the atmosphere is about forty-three dollars. (Obviously there is a huge standard of error on this number, but let’s just run with it.) If that number is right, then the gas tax needed to offset the global warming effect is about twelve cents per gallon. According to a
National Academy of Sciences report
, American motor vehicles burn about 160 billion gallons of gasoline and diesel each year. At twelve cents a gallon, that implies a $20 billion global warming externality. So relative to reducing congestion and lowering the number of accidents, fighting global warming is a distant third in terms of reasons to raise the gas tax. (Not that $20 billion is a small number; it just highlights how high the costs are from congestion and accidents.)

Combining all these numbers, along with the other reasons why we should raise the gas tax (e.g., wear and tear on roads), it seems easy to justify raising the gas tax by at least one dollar per gallon. In 2002 (
the year I could easily find data for
), the average tax was forty-two cents per gallon, or maybe only one-third of what it should be.

High gas prices act just like taxes, except that they are more transitory and the extra revenue goes to oil producers, refiners, and distributors instead of to the government.

My view is that, rather than bemoaning the high price of gas, we should be celebrating it. And, if any presidential candidate should come out in favor of a one-dollar-per-gallon tax on gas, vote for that candidate.

One hidden consequence of high gas prices: they lead to more traffic fatalities as drivers opt for smaller, fuel-efficient cars—and, increasingly, motorcycles. A 2014 study in the journal
Injury Prevention
found that in California alone, a thirty-cent-per-gallon rise in gas prices led to an extra eight hundred motorbike-related deaths over a nine-year period.

CHAPTER 4
Contested

©iStock.com/ChrisGorgio

Every time we write a book, our publisher prints up a bunch of swag—T-shirts, posters, etc.—to use as promotion. They send us a few boxes, which inevitably wind up in a closet. One day we were thinking: How can we give this stuff away to people who might actually want it? That’s when we decided to run our first blog contest, with the winner getting a piece of swag. These contests were so much fun—our blog readers are extraordinarily ingenious—that we held dozens of them. Here are a few of our favorites.

What Is the Most Addictive Thing in the World?
(SDL)

I was talking with my colleague and friend Gary Becker a while back about addiction. Among his many other accomplishments, for which he has won a Nobel, Becker introduced the idea of
rational addiction
.

When he told me his opinion as to the most addictive good, I was initially surprised and skeptical. On further reflection, I believe he is right.

So here is the quiz: What does Gary Becker think is the most addictive thing on earth?

THE FOLLOWING DAY
. . .

More than six hundred readers took a shot at guessing what Gary Becker thinks is the most addictive thing on earth.

Lots of folks said things like crack and caffeine, but do you really think I’m going to offer a blog quiz with an obvious answer?

While not the answer I was looking for, there was something poetic about Deb’s guess:

A yawn. A smile. Salt.

Before I give the answer, it is worth thinking about what it means for a good to be addictive. At least the way I think about it, an addictive thing has the following characteristics:

        
1
. Once you start consuming it, you want to consume more and more of it.

        
2
. Over time you build up a tolerance to it; i.e., you get less enjoyment out of consuming a fixed amount of it.

        
3
. Pursuit of that good leads you to sacrifice everything else in your life to get it, potentially leading you to do ridiculous things to try to get the good.

        
4
. There is a period of withdrawal when you stop consuming the good.

No doubt alcohol and crack cocaine fit that description well. In Becker’s view, however, there is something even more addictive than substances: people.

When he first said this, it sounded kind of crazy to me. What does it mean to say that people are addictive?

Then I thought more about it, and I think he is right. Falling in love is the ultimate addiction. There is no question that in the early stages of attraction, spending a little bit of time with someone makes you desperately want more. Infatuation can be all-encompassing, and people will do anything to make a relationship blossom. They will risk everything and often end up looking utterly foolish. Once someone is in a relationship, however, the utility he or she derives from time with the beloved diminishes. The heady excitement of courtship gives way to something much more mundane. Even if a relationship isn’t that good, for at least one of the parties there is a painful withdrawal period.

To get the exact answer I was looking for took until comment number 343, when Bobo responded ”Other People.” Many others were close. Jeff (comment 13) said “Society or human companionship.” Laura (comment 47) said “Love.”

I’ll declare all three of them winners.

The Unintended Consequences of a Twitter Contest
(SJD)

The other day, we woke up to realize that we were about hit our four-hundred-thousandth Twitter follower. So we put out the following tweet, offering some Freakonomics swag as a reward:

@freakonomics

We’re at 399,987 Twitter followers. Thanks everyone!

Follower #400,000 will get Freakonomics swag!

Innocent enough, no?

But we had walked right into an incentive trap.

We monitored our Twitter status in order to identify the four-hundred-thousandth follower. It happened very fast, as new followers were signing up at what seemed to be a rate of five or six per second. So we counted carefully and, voilà, found our winner:

@freakonomics

@emeganboggs
You’re our
400,000th Twitter follower
!

Congrats! Contest is over, thanks everyone!

But then, when we went back to our main Twitter page, we found that we were
below
the four-hundred-thousand mark, by quite a bit. In fact, we had fewer followers after the contest than before.

So what happened?

If you’re a Twitter pro, you’ve probably already figured it out. Our offer of
swag
created an incentive to unfollow and then refollow our feed. Appropriately enough, our followers informed us, and promptly:

@GuinevereXandra

@freakonomics
isn’t my incentive then to unfollow and refollow and repeat until i get to 400,000?

 

@Schrodert

@freakonomics
And the de-follows into re-follows begin!

 

@Keyes

@freakonomics
Hah, there go twenty of your followers. Like the twitter version of those penny-a-bid auctions.

 

@ChaseRoper

@freakonomics
you just created an incentive for followers to unfollow and try to re-follow in order to be #400K.

I wish I could say this was a clever experiment but in fact it was simply a good lesson in Twitter incentives. So the person we thought was our four-hundred-thousandth follower, @emeganboggs, wasn’t. We’ll still send her some swag, but we’ll also send some to a couple other people who actually were around the four hundred thousand mark. Even if they did unfollow us to get there :-). Thanks to everyone for a fun day on Twitter and yet another good lesson in unintended consequences.

Contest: A Six-Word Motto for the U.S.?
(SJD)

Inspired by a recent trip to London and a (New York)
Times
article
about England’s reluctant search for a national motto (suggestions include “No Motto Please, We’re British” and “One Mighty Empire, Slightly Used”), as well as by
a new book on six-word memoirs
for which I wrote a piece (“On the seventh word, he rested”), I invite you all to attempt the following:

Write a six-word motto for the U.S. of A.

Foreign players are most welcome. Feel free to punctuate your motto liberally (or, if you will, conservatively); for instance: “Battered? A bit. Beaten? Puh-leeze. Onward!”

TWO WEEKS LATER
. . .

Your response to our motto contest was quite strong, with more than 1,200 replies to date. Anyone looking for a good snapshot of public sentiment during
this most interesting election year
[2008] would do well to scroll through the comments: they are pretty damn illuminating, and not remotely sanguine.

The earliest comments tended to lean fairly hard to the left. Then, apparently because the contest was picked up on some right-leaning blogs, a long round of corrective mottoes came pouring in. Upon entering this fray, a cynic might give our motto contest the following motto:

Leftists Whine; Rightists Parry; Bedlam Accomplished

Or perhaps this:

Dead Split Between Patriots and Hatriots

Considering that this blog at least occasionally concerns itself with economics, I was surprised there weren’t more suggestions having to do with free markets, maybe something like . . .

Creative Destruction
at Its Very Finest

In the end, there were so many good, thoughtful, funny, heartfelt, and nasty suggestions that it was self-evidently beyond our ability to just pick a winner. So we narrowed the entries to the following five finalists. Please vote for your choice below, and the motto with the most votes within forty-eight hours will be declared the winner.

        
1
. The Most Gentle Empire So Far

        
2
. You Should See the Other Guy

        
3
. Caution! Experiment in Progress Since 1776

        
4
. Just Like Canada, with Better Bacon

        
5
. Our Worst Critics Prefer to Stay

A WEEK LATER
. . .

As promised, we tallied your votes for a new six-word motto for the U.S. The winner was clear:

Our Worst Critics Prefer to Stay (194 votes)

Here are the runners-up:

Caution! Experiment in Progress Since 1776 (134)

The Most Gentle Empire So Far (64)

You Should See the Other Guy (38)

Just Like Canada, with Better Bacon (18)

I applaud your choice of winner, and I especially applaud “edholston,” who wrote the motto. “Our Worst Critics Prefer to Stay” is, while perhaps not outright uplifting, a wonderfully concise acknowledgment of the paradox that a capitalist democracy inevitably is: a place that is often well worth complaining about, and which allows you to complain as loudly as you wish.

It seems a small reward to get just a piece of Freakonomics swag for such a mighty task as writing a new motto for the United States, but that is all we have to offer. That, and our thanks—to Ed, and to all of you who participated.

Now, who among you can see about actually getting this motto adopted?

BOOK: When to Rob a Bank: ...And 131 More Warped Suggestions and Well-Intended Rants
8.12Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

Other books

Jessica's Wolves by Becca Jameson
Chloe’s New Beginning by Alicia White
A Diamond in the Dark by Sassie Lewis
Little House On The Prairie by Wilder, Laura Ingalls
Unleashed by Katie MacAlister
Homecoming Day by Holly Jacobs
Sweet Discipline by Bonnie Hamre
The Adultery Club by Tess Stimson