A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II (57 page)

BOOK: A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II
9.79Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

the leading fugleman and interpreter of the Genoa resolutions.55

The currency resolutions of the Genoa Conference, which formed the European monetary system of the 1920s, called for a stable currency value in each country, and for the establishment of central banks everywhere: “in countries where there is no central bank of issue, one should be established.” These central banks, not only in Europe but elsewhere (particularly the United States) should practice “continuous cooperation” in order to bring about and maintain “currency reform.” The conference suggested an early formal meeting of central banks and an international convention to launch this coordination. The currencies of Europe should be on a common standard, which at present would have to be gold. After expressing a desire for balanced budgets in each nation, the conference declared that some countries would need foreign loans to attain stabilization.

Fixing the value of the currency unit in gold was left, by the conference, to each country, and the resolutions were vague on the criteria to be used.

Resolution 9 looked specifically to a new form of gold standard, which would

centralize and coordinate the demand for gold, and so . . .

avoid those wide fluctuations in the purchasing power of gold which might otherwise result from the simultaneous and competitive efforts of a number of countries to secure metallic reserves.

In other words, to fix and
raise
price levels above the free market, and in particular to try to avoid redemption in gold and 55See Ralph G. Hawtrey, “The Genoa Resolutions on Currency,”
Economic Journal
32 (1922): 290–304, included in Ralph G. Hawtrey,
Monetary Reconstruction
(London: Longmans, Green, 1923), pp. 131–47.

The text of the Genoa resolutions themselves can be found in the
Federal
Reserve Bulletin
(June 1922): 678–79, reprinted in Joseph Stagg Lawrence,
Stabilization of Prices
(New York: Macmillan, 1928), pp. 162–65.

394

A History of Money and Banking in the United States:
The Colonial Era to World War II

subsequent contraction of overexpanded paper currencies. Resolution 9 then became specific: the point was to economize “the use of gold by maintaining reserves in the form of foreign balances, such, for example, as the gold-exchange standard or an international clearing system.” Resolution 11 spelled out the gold-exchange system in detail, and also declares that credit will be regulated not only to keep the various currencies at par, “but also with a view of preventing undue fluctuations in the purchasing power of gold,” that is, the stabilizationist program of fixing (and raising) prices higher than free-market levels.

In particular, in Resolution 11, “the maintenance of the currency at its gold value must be assured by the provision of an adequate reserve of approved assets, not necessarily gold.” In more detail:

A participating country, in addition to any gold reserve held at home, may maintain in any other participating country reserves of approved assets in the form of bank balances, bills, short-term securities, or other suitable liquid resources.

And:

The ordinary practice of a participating country will be to buy and sell exchange on other participating countries within a prescribed fraction of parity of exchange for its own currency on demand.

The
gold
aspect of this scheme is covered in the clause: “When progress permits, certain of the participating countries (i.e., Great Britain, and the U.S., if it participates) will establish a free market in gold and thus become gold centers.” The upshot, the currency resolution concludes, is that “the convention will thus be based on a gold exchange standard.”56

Ralph Hawtrey’s essay on behalf of the Genoa system is instructive in many ways. Most of it is devoted to defending the idea of coordinated central bank action, that is, essentially 56Lawrence,
Stabilization of Prices
, p. 164.

The Gold-Exchange Standard in the Interwar Years
395

monetary expansion, to stabilize the price level. Hawtrey asks the crucial question:

It may be asked, why is any international agreement on the subject of the gold standard necessary at all? When we have once got a currency based on commodity like gold, why should we not rely on free market conditions, as we did before the war?57

Why indeed? Why can’t the new pseudo gold standard be like the old? Hawtrey makes it clear that his reason is a phobia about deflation. The paper money stock had multiplied since 1914, and therefore there “has been a great fall in the commodity value of gold.” Even in late 1922, after the price fall of the 1921 recession, the value of the gold dollar was “only two-thirds of what it was before the war.” Hence, the “danger” of a scramble to secure gold, and a contraction of money and prices. But what is so terrible about deflation? Here, Hawtrey avoids even mentioning the wage rigidity and the unemployment insurance system that had changed the economic face of Britain. He simply points to the “notorious . . . chronic state of depression which prevailed during the spread of the gold standard in the period 1873–1896.” This is really his only horrible example.

But, in the first place, Hawtrey is wrong in attributing falling prices during the late nineteenth century to a shift from silver to gold. The falling prices were due to the industrial revolution, and the phenomenal advance of productivity, and hence a drop in price levels, during this period. But a more important error is that Hawtrey has made the all-too-common modern error of identifying falling prices with “depression.” In reality, production and living standards were progressing, in Britain and the United States, during this period, costs were falling and therefore there was no squeeze on profits. The era of falling prices was not a “depression” at all, and was only 57Hawtrey,
Monetary Reconstruction
, pp. 134–35.

396

A History of Money and Banking in the United States:
The Colonial Era to World War II

experienced as such decades later by historians who fail to understand the social benefits of falling prices.58

Second, in his exegesis Hawtrey lets the cat out of the bag.

He virtually concedes that his ideal is to abandon gold altogether, and remain with only managed fiat money. Thus, in discussing the key currency countries, Hawtrey states wistfully,

“At the gold centres some gold reserves must be maintained.” But if the gold standard becomes worldwide, “if all the gold standard countries adhere to it, gold will nowhere be needed as a means of remittance, and gold will only be withdrawn from the reserves for use as a raw material of industry.”59 In short, Hawtrey looked forward to dispensing with gold as a monetary metal altogether, and to have the world solely on a fiat paper standard.

Hawtrey concludes his essay by conceding that there was only one defect in the Genoa resolutions: that there was no mention of how long it would take to return to gold. Even the strongest countries, he emphasized, would have to wait until their currencies rose on the exchange market to equal their designated rates. To induce a rise in pound sterling to meet the high fixed rate, Britain would either have to deflate, or else foreign countries, especially the United States, would have to inflate to correct the international discrepancy. “Further deflation,” declaimed Hawtrey, “is out of the question.” Therefore the only hope was to “stabilize our currency at its existing purchasing power,” and wait for the increased gold supply in the United States to lead to a substantial inflation in the United States.60 Like the other British leaders, Hawtrey was pinning his faith on Uncle Sam’s inflating enough to “help Britain.”61

58Thus, see the illuminating work by S.B. Saul,
The Myth of the Great
Depression, 1873–1896
(London: Macmillan, 1969).

59Hawtrey,
Monetary Reconstruction
, p. 136.

60Ibid., p. 147.

61For contemporaneous critiques of Hawtrey’s stabilizationism as a mask for inflationism, see Lawrence,
Stabilization of Prices
, pp. 326, 432–33;
The Gold-Exchange Standard in the Interwar Years
397

Many historians have written off the Genoa Conference as a

“failure” and dismissed its influence on the international money of the twentieth century. It is true that the formal institutions of central bank cooperation called for at Genoa were not established, largely because of the reluctance of the United States.

But the critical point is that Genoa triumphed anyway, since Benjamin Strong was willing to perform the same tasks in informal but highly effective central bank cooperation to establish and prop up Britain’s pseudo gold standard. Strong’s reluctance stemmed from two sources: an understandable fear that isolationist and antibank sentiment would raise a firestorm against any formal collaboration with European central banks—especially in an America that had reacted against the formal foreign interventionism of the League of Nations. And second, Strong actually preferred the full gold standard, and was queasy about the inflationary unsoundness of a gold-exchange standard. But his reluctance did not prevent him from collaborating closely in support of his friend Montagu Norman and of their common Morgan connection. Their collaboration constituted, in the words of Michael Hogan, an “informal entente.”62 Actually, what Strong preferred was close “key currency” collaboration between, say, the central banks of the United States, England, and France, rather than to be outvoted at formal international conventions.63

In fact, after international commodity prices began to decline in 1926, Norman became more frantic in pursuing formal meetings of central bankers, and more insistent on continuing and and Patrick Deutscher,
R.G. Hawtrey and the Development of Macroeconomics
(Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1990), pp. 211–15.

62Michael J. Hogan,
Informal Entente: The Private Structure of
Cooperation in Anglo-American Economic Diplomacy, 1918–1928
(Columbia: University of Missouri Press, 1977). On Strong’s misgivings on the gold-exchange system, see Stephen V.O. Clarke,
Central Bank Cooperation,
1924–31
(New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1967), pp. 36–40.

63Clarke,
Central Bank Cooperation
, pp. 40–41.

398

A History of Money and Banking in the United States:
The Colonial Era to World War II

intensifying the inflationary thrust of the gold-exchange standard. Finally, with the establishment of the Bank for International Settlements at Geneva in 1930, Norman at least succeeded in having regular monthly meetings of central bankers.64

Far from Genoa being merely a flash in the pan, the 1922 conference placed its decisive stamp upon the postwar monetary world. In the words of Professor Davis, “the widespread adoption of the Gold Exchange Standard can be seen as the legacy of Genoa.”65

Following the Genoa model, Great Britain, as we have seen, set up the gold-exchange system by returning to its new version of gold in 1925; the other European countries, as well as other nations, followed, each at its own pace. By early 1926, some form of gold standard was established, at least de facto, in 39

countries. By 1928, 43 nations were de jure on the gold standard.

Of these, even the few allegedly on the gold bullion standard such as France, kept most of their reserves in sterling balances in London, and the same is true of officially gold-coin nations such as the Netherlands. Apart from the United States, the only officially gold-coin countries were minor nations on the world periphery, such as Mexico, Colombia, Cuba, and the Union of South Africa.66 It should be noted that Norway and Denmark, who insisted in following the Genoa path of struggling back to gold at a highly overvalued currency, suffered, like Britain, from an export depression throughout the 1920s; whereas Finland, acting on better advice, went back at a realistically devalued rate, and avoided chronic depression during this period.67

64Ibid., p. 36.

65Davis, “R.G. Hawtrey,” p. 232, n. 74.

66Palyi,
Twilight of Gold,
pp. 116–17, 107.

67Finland acted on the advice of the great classical liberal Swedish economic historian, Professor Eli Heckscher of the University of Stockholm. See Richard A. Lester, “The Gold Parity Depression in Norway and Denmark, 1924–1928,”
Journal of Political Economy
(August 1937): 433–67; and Palyi,
Twilight of Gold
, pp. 73, 107.

The Gold-Exchange Standard in the Interwar Years
399

Throughout Europe, Great Britain, wielding its control of the Finance Committee of the League of Nations, engineered the stabilization of currencies on a gold-exchange, that is, a sterling-exchange standard: in Germany, Austria, Hungary, Estonia, Bulgaria, Greece, Belgium, Poland, and Latvia. New central banks were established in the nations of Eastern Europe, basing themselves on reserves in sterling, with British supervisors and directors installed in those banks.68

Emile Moreau, the shrewd governor of the Bank of France, recorded his analysis of this British monetary power play in his diary:

England having been the first European country to reestablish a stable and secure money has used that advantage to establish a basis for putting Europe under a veritable financial domination. The Financial Committee [of the League of Nations] at Geneva has been the instrument of that policy.

The method consists of forcing every country in monetary difficulty to subject itself to the Committee at Geneva, which the British control. The remedies prescribed always involve the installation in the central bank of a foreign supervisor who is British or designated by the Bank of England, and the deposit of a part of the reserve of the central bank at the Bank of England, which serves both to support the pound and to fortify British influence. To guarantee against possible failure they are careful to secure the cooperation of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Moreover, they pass on to America the task of making some of the foreign loans if they seem too heavy, always retaining the political advantages of these operations.69

Other books

Tokyo Surprise by Alex Ko
On Dangerous Ground by Jack Higgins
The Danger of Being Me by Anthony J Fuchs
Hawk's Way Grooms by Joan Johnston
Willow Grove Abbey by Mary Christian Payne
Beds and Blazes by Bebe Balocca
Cold Rain by Craig Smith
Everything Changes by Jonathan Tropper
The Apartment: A Novel by Greg Baxter
Let Loose the Dogs by Maureen Jennings