Read Power Hungry Online

Authors: Robert Bryce

Power Hungry (36 page)

BOOK: Power Hungry
3.05Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads
Although N2N is the obvious way forward, we must be realistic. Adding significant quantities of new nuclear power capacity in the United States will take decades. In the meantime, the United States should focus on the first N: natural gas. But emphasizing natural gas will be difficult, particularly given the strength of the coal lobby in Congress. It will also require Congress and federal regulators to overcome a decades-long parade of bad legislation that has had the perverse effect of stifling U.S. natural gas production and reducing gas's share of the U.S. primary energy market. Much of that legislation was based on a mistaken notion that America's natural gas resources were running out.
Thus, before looking forward to what should happen next with the U.S. gas sector, we need to take a quick look back at the history of an energy source that was once viewed as being nearly worthless.
CHAPTER 22
A Very Short History of American Natural Gas and Regulatory Stupidity
The choice is not between cheap and expensive natural gas, because there is no such thing as a plentiful supply of cheap gas.
Editorial,
Los Angeles Times
, May 26, 1975
1
F
OR DECADES, the calculus in the oil field was simple: Oil was cash. Natural gas was trash.
Oil was easily transported—by pipeline, rail, or truck—and it had a huge and growing market in the burgeoning fleet of trucks and automobiles. It could also be used for manufacturing, lubrication, heating, cooking, and lighting. Oil was relatively easy to handle. If a well blew out, the petroleum could be diverted into a hastily dug pit. Longer-term storage could be handled with relatively inexpensive wooden tanks, which would suffice until the oil could be transported.
Gas, on the other hand, was difficult to transport and had a nasty habit of exploding. The fuel could only be profitably moved by pipeline, and other than heating and municipal lighting systems—which required good pipelines—it had few apparent uses. That meant the fuel was nearly worthless to the oil companies—and in the early days of the industry, that's what they were, oil companies. Few companies targeted natural gas
when drilling. Instead, they were forced to deal with the natural gas that was mixed with the oil. In the industry, that type of gas is known as “associated gas.” And given that it was mixed with oil and was hard to get rid of, it was viewed as more of a problem than an asset. Thus, during the first few decades of the U.S. oil industry, there was no “gas industry” to speak of. The idea of actually drilling for natural gas on purpose—or, in industry parlance, looking for “unassociated gas”—was rare.
A few entrepreneurs did see value in natural gas. In 1891, America's first significant high-pressure gas pipeline was built by Indiana Gas and Oil to carry natural gas from a field in Indiana to customers in Chicago, a distance of about 120 miles. However, the pipe was a leaky mess, and by 1907, it was shut down. Two decades later, there were only a handful of natural gas pipelines in the entire country, and many of them were plagued by leaks and inefficient operations. It wasn't until the early 1920s—when manufacturers began making significant quantities of seamless steel pipe, which could be joined using new technologies such as oxyacetylene and electric welding—that pipeline builders were able to string together longer sections of high-strength steel pipe.
2
But even with those technologies, by the mid-1920s the longest gas pipeline in the United States was only about 300 miles long.
By 1930, when oil was selling for about $1 per barrel, natural gas was selling in some locales for as little as $0.03 per thousand cubic feet—if a market for the gas was even available.
3
With scant pipeline capacity and little monetary interest in selling the gas, most producers looked for ways to simply get rid of the fuel. During the 1940s, gas was so abundant in the areas around Amarillo, Texas, that the city offered companies free natural gas for five years if they agreed to set up shop in the city and employ at least fifty people.
4
The city got no takers. With few uses for the gas, huge quantities of the fuel were simply vented into the atmosphere. That worked, but it also came with the risk of explosion. (Furthermore, we now know that methane is a greenhouse gas that is about twenty times more effective at trapping heat in the atmosphere than carbon dioxide.)
It was both safer and better, from an environmental standpoint, to burn the gas near the wellhead. Companies with too much gas on their hands put up tall pipes near their producing wells and set the gas aflame.
During the 1930s and 1940s in Texas, gas flares were so common, and so bright, that in parts of the Lone Star State motorists could drive for hours at night without ever needing to flip on their headlights. According to historian David Prindle, “Miles away from any major oil field, newspapers could be read at night by the light” from the flares. In 1934 alone, about 1 billion cubic feet of gas per day were being flared in the Texas Panhandle.
5
Flaring might have continued but for the intervention of the Texas Railroad Commission, the Austin-based agency that from the 1930s through 1973 determined production levels for key U.S. oil fields, which had the effect of largely determining global oil prices. In 1947, after years of wrangling with the industry, the agency passed a rule that prohibited the flaring of gas. The agency determined that gas was a valuable natural resource and therefore should be conserved.
6
Some producers fought the rule, but the courts sided with the agency. The Railroad Commission's move forced Texas producers to either reinject the natural gas into their wells—a move that helped to maintain the oil reservoir's natural pressure, and therefore its long-term productivity—or put it into a pipeline.
7
The ban on flaring was later adopted by other oil-producing states in the United States, and the domestic gas industry began to mature.
Between 1949 and 1957, U.S. gas consumption doubled, and in 1958, gas surpassed coal to become the second-largest source of primary energy in the country.
8
By the late 1950s, gas looked ready to rob even greater market share away from coal. But just as that energy transition was beginning, natural gas became a favored target for federal regulators. And the hodgepodge of regulations that resulted would hamstring the U.S. gas industry for decades. The result was predictable: U.S. gas consumption fell, coal consumption rose, and along with increased coal use came increased emissions of carbon dioxide.
The case was known as
Phillips Petroleum Co. v. Wisconsin
. In 1954, just four years before natural gas eclipsed coal as the second-biggest source of primary energy in the United States, the U.S. Supreme Court issued a ruling in the Phillips case that gave federal authorities the power to set
prices on gas that was sold into the interstate market. Federal regulators were empowered to set prices based on the gas producers' costs, plus a “fair” profit.
9
But the prices deemed “fair” by federal regulators were often uneconomic for gas producers. The result was a downward spiral in the amount of gas destined for sale across state lines. Gas producers could sell their production to customers inside their own state (intrastate) for a mutually agreed-on price. But if those same producers—say, from gasrich states such as Oklahoma or Texas—wanted to sell their gas to a pipeline for delivery to customers in, say, Ohio or Illinois, then that interstate gas was subject to federal price controls. In short, the price controls effectively prevented producers from sending their gas to the most lucrative markets, and that, predictably, slowed the growth of the U.S. gas industry.
By 1971, a shortage of natural gas was looming. That year, Monty Hoyt, a reporter for the
Christian Science Monitor
, summed up the situation: “The wellhead price for interstate natural gas has been kept artificially low for more than a decade” by federal regulators, and “this has stimulated demand for the ‘Mr. Clean' of fuels, while at the same time discouraging exploration and drilling of new wells. Reserves have dwindled as a result.” He went on to say that “cheap natural gas has caused utilities and major industries to switch to gas-burning boilers,” a move that depressed demand for other boiler fuels such as coal and oil.
10
In January 1973, the
Washington Post
reported that the United States was in the midst of a “chronic shortage of natural gas,” and when a cold snap hit the nation that month, energy shortages were widespread. Schools and factories in eleven states, from Colorado to Ohio, were forced to close. Homeowners in several states, including Michigan, Minnesota, and Illinois, were running short of natural gas. The havoc wasn't limited to natural gas. Price controls imposed by the Nixon administration on refined oil products led to widespread shortages.
11
But despite the recurring shortages, some of the energy industry's loudest critics simply couldn't fathom the concept that government price controls might be the problem rather than the solution. In 1974, S. David Freeman, a lawyer who later became the head of the Tennessee Valley Authority, wrote an opinion piece for the
Los Angeles Times
, in which he insisted that price controls on natural gas were essential and must be
continued. His solution to America's energy crisis was more governmental intervention to the point where the government, he said, would “provide everyone with a smaller ration of gasoline.”
12
Fortunately, Freeman's grand plan for rationing motor fuel didn't gain any traction. But his belief in the need to keep energy scarce and expensive gained plenty of traction in California. About seven months after Freeman wrote his piece for the
Los Angeles Times
, the paper's editorial board published its own piece, arguing that natural gas prices should be deregulated—but only for “new gas.” That is, any gas discoveries that were made from 1975 onward should be allowed to sell their gas “in a fundamentally free market.” But existing gas supplies would continue to be sold at prices set by federal regulators. The
Times
went on to contend that a “windfall profits tax” should be imposed on the gas producers who “failed to plow most of the profits back into the hunt for new supplies.” The editors concluded their May 26, 1975, opinion piece by declaring that “the choice is not between cheap and expensive natural gas, because there is no such thing as a plentiful supply of cheap gas.”
13
That belief—that there's no such thing as a plentiful supply of cheap gas—continued to be the dominant mindset throughout the mid- to late 1970s. And that mindset assured that the federal price controls stayed in place. In January 1977, when the United States was hit by another blast of nasty winter weather, natural gas shortages came roaring back. The shortages were so severe that a utility in Buffalo, New York, asked its business, industrial, and school customers to shut down for two days and suggested that residential customers turn their thermostats down to 55 degrees. In Ohio, gas utilities were forced to cut off supplies to 4,500 industrial customers, and automobile plants in Michigan and Ohio were closed, putting 56,000 people out of work.
14
By late January, some 300,000 workers had been laid off as a result of the shortages of natural gas. The crisis was so acute that on January 26, 1977, President Jimmy Carter, who'd just been sworn into office about a week earlier, asked Congress for emergency legislation that would temporarily lift the federal price controls on interstate gas shipments.
15
Throughout the late 1970s, ideologues such as Freeman and other Carter-era energy bureaucrats were convinced that there was a geological shortage of natural gas and therefore the United States had to embark
on an alternative path away from the fuel. In 1977, John O'Leary, the administrator of the Federal Energy Administration, told Congress that “it must be assumed that domestic natural gas supplies will continue to decline” and that the United States should “convert to other fuels just as rapidly as we can.” That same year, Gordon Zareski of the Federal Power Commission testified before Congress and stated that U.S. policies “should be based on the expectation of decreasing gas availability.” He went on to say that annual production of natural gas would “continue to decline, even assuming successful exploration and development of the frontier areas.”
16
What O'Leary and Zareski didn't tell Congress was that within gasrich states such as Texas, there was a surfeit of gas. Why? The answer was simple: Gas producers could get good prices for their product by keeping it within the state's borders. In mid-1973, when federal interstate prices were about $0.25 per thousand cubic feet, some Texas producers were selling their production intrastate for as much as $0.82.
17
By 1978, Texas had so much gas in its intrastate market that the Texas Railroad Commission began acting as a type of referee for the intrastate sales so that it could more closely match output with demand.
18
The havoc caused by federal meddling in the interstate gas market was recognized by energy-industry historian Ruth Sheldon Knowles, who, in a 1977 opinion piece for the
Los Angeles Times
, wrote that “the nation's natural gas shortage was created by interstate controls. By contrast, the free-market approach has actually increased supplies for intrastate use.” The reason federal price controls on interstate gas persisted was that “keeping the price artificially low—that is, below its true market value—has been politically popular.”
19
BOOK: Power Hungry
3.05Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

Other books

Sheikh And The Princess 1 by Kimaya Mathew
A Glimpse of Fire by Debbi Rawlins
Amongst Women by John McGahern
Protector by Catherine Mann
The Mysterious Island by Tony Abbott
13 - The Rainbow Affair by David McDaniel