Read Bailout Nation Online

Authors: Barry Ritholtz

Bailout Nation (26 page)

BOOK: Bailout Nation
11.48Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads
There are two superpowers in the world today in my opinion. There's the United States and there's Moody's bond rating service. The United States can destroy you by dropping bombs, and Moody's can destroy you by downgrading your bonds. And believe me, it's not clear sometimes who's more powerful.
5
Friedman was exaggerating, but only by a little bit. As the power of Moody's, S&P, and their smaller rival Fitch continued to grow, it attracted the attention of federal regulators.
As SEC Commissioner Paul Atkins said in a 2008 speech:
Subsequently, NRSRO ratings were incorporated into additional SEC regulations, gaining momentum with Rule 2a-7, which governs which assets may be held in a money-market mutual fund. Rule 2a-7 was promulgated in the early 1990s when some funds came close to breaking a dollar of net asset value because of declining values of certain riskier securities that they held in their portfolios. The new rule looked to
high-rated debt instruments
as suitable investments for money-market funds.
6
(emphasis added)
In essence, a ruling that began in 1975 with good intentions (measure and limit the risk taken by investment banks) granted tremendous power to a small number of credit rating agencies. Those firms became the ultimate arbiters of what mutual funds, money market funds, banks, brokers, and a whole host of other investors could or could not own. Not content with their “superpower” status, the rating agencies ultimately sought “super profits.” They were one of the great enablers of the derivatives mania of this decade.
Although the rating agencies had been feckless in accurately assessing the credit quality of Enron (Aaa until just prior to its bankruptcy), investors around the world deluded themselves into believing all manner of CDOs, CMOs, RMBSs, and other toxic securities were really of triple-A quality because rating agencies said so. These NRSROs had been blessed by the government to have the official word on such matters, so very few people questioned the veracity of the process.
“You have legitimized these things, leading people into dangerous risk,” an executive with Fortis Investments, a money management firm, wrote in a July 2007 e-mail message to Moody's.
7
A
ctions have consequences. Denying reality, falsifying data, gaming the numbers, cooking the books, making believe inflation is more modest than it really is, or pretending toxic assets deserve the highest credit ratings all have real-world consequences, intended and otherwise.
Chapter 13
Moral Hazard: Why Bailouts Cause Future Problems
To be sure, some moral hazard, however slight, may have been created by the Federal Reserve's involvement. [Such negatives were outweighed by the risk of] serious distortions to market prices had Long-Term
[
Capital Management
]
been pushed suddenly into bankruptcy.
—Alan Greenspan
1
 
 
W
hat is moral hazard? During this past year of our bailout, the phrase has been bandied about haphazardly. Let's define this important term before proceeding further.
Moral hazard is “the prospect that a party insulated from risk may behave differently from the way they would if they were otherwise fully exposed to that risk. It arises when an individual or institution does not bear the full consequences of its actions, and therefore tends to act less carefully than they otherwise would, leaving a third party to bear the responsibility for the consequences of those actions.”
2
That's the formal definition. E. S. Browning, writing in the
Wall Street Journal
, used this less complicated description:
Moral hazard is an old economic concept with its roots in the insurance business. The idea goes like this: If you protect someone too well against an unwanted outcome, that person may behave recklessly. Someone who buys extensive liability insurance for his car may drive too fast because he feels financially protected.
3
Hence, there is very real concern that the many bailouts of 2008 and 2009 are creating moral hazard, encouraging more reckless behavior in the future.
Consider the Greenspan quote at the beginning of this chapter; I first came across it in Roger Lowenstein's
When Genius Failed: The Rise and Fall of Long-Term Capital Management
. Rest assured that LTCM did not present, as Greenspan claimed after LTCM's rescue, only “slight” moral hazard. The collapse of that hedge fund in 1998 and its subsequent Fed-orchestrated rescue plan provided one of the greatest—and most terrible—examples of moral hazard ever known.
As noted in Chapter 6, LTCM used enormous amounts of leverage. The fund's traders applied complex quantitative strategies, using over $100 billion in borrowed capital to buy thinly traded assets that were hard to value. Overall, the entire operation was highly dependent on global liquidity.
Gee, that sounds vaguely familiar.
Leverage, complexity, thin trading, difficult-to-value, liquidity dependent—it's as if the trading gods are mocking those managers who came after LTCM and managed to lose billions upon billions of dollars anyway. How on earth could the lessons of LTCM be missed? One can imagine the booming voice of the Almighty, both amused by and annoyed at these traders: “You want a sign? How much more of a sign do you idiots need? I never should have taught you primates to wear pants. There are smarter chimpanzees running naked in Africa than you morons.”
At least, that's how I imagine it.
Contrary to what Greenspan claimed, the Federal Reserve's involvement did not create “slight” moral hazard. Rather, the 1998 Fed-orchestrated rescue was moral hazard writ humongous. Lowenstein presciently wrote the following in 2000:
If one looks at the Long-Term episode in isolation, one would tend to agree that the Fed was right to intervene, just as, if confronted with a suddenly mentally unstable patient, most doctors would willingly prescribe a tranquilizer. The risks of a breakdown are immediate; those of addiction are long term.
But the Long-Term Capital case must be seen for what it is: not an isolated instance but the latest in a series in which an agency of the government has come to the rescue of private speculators.
...
It is true that the Fed's involvement was limited and that no government money was used. But the banks would not have come together without the enormous power and influence of the Fed behind them, and without a joint effort, Long-Term surely would have collapsed. Presumably, the banks and others would have suffered more severe losses—though not, one thinks, as great as some suggested. Long-Term's exposure was huge, but, spread over all of Wall Street, it was hardly of apocalyptic proportions.
...
Permitting such losses to occur is what deters most other people and institutions from taking imprudent risks. Now especially, after a decade of prosperity and buoyant financial markets, a reminder that foolishness carries a price would be no bad thing. Will investors in the next problem-child-to-be, having been lulled by the soft landing engineered for Long-Term, be counting on the Fed, too? On balance, the Fed's decision to get involved—though understandable given the panicky conditions of September 1998—regrettably squandered a choice opportunity to send the markets a needed dose of discipline.
4
We now know the answers to Lowenstein's rhetorical question: Yes, they most certainly were counting on the Fed. And, we know precisely what that next problem child was—the many mortgage-backed bonds and credit default swap bets upon them. Further, we have witnessed investors lulled from 2005 to 2007 into what I have described elsewhere as a “stupefying complacency.”
To be certain, the management of large investment banks missed the obvious lesson here; as soon as they were able to, they willingly leveraged up nearly as much as LTCM had. When one considers the astonishing parallels between that past crisis and the current one, the missed opportunity for a “dose of [market] discipline” is all the more regrettable.
Had Long-Term Capital Management been allowed to fail, it's quite possible the worst of the current credit crisis, regulatory fecklessness, and speculator recklessness could have been avoided. Instead, there was a massive, cascading systemwide failure. At every point along the way, from home purchases in Stockton, California, to Iceland's fiscal demise, things went awry.
So much for the lessons learned.
L
TCM was not the only missed opportunity to teach a lesson about moral hazard. Other bailouts continue to leave lasting, negative effects on future behaviors, including a lack of discipline across many industries.
Recall the original 1980 Chrysler bailout. Since then, the Detroit automakers have seen their market share tumble from 74 percent of autos sold in the United States to 47 percent; the UAW has since lost over two-thirds of the 1.5 million members the union had back in 1980. That was
with
a bailout. Would they really have fared much worse had circumstances been allowed to run their natural course (i.e., without government interference)? Perhaps this is why the first bailout proposal for Detroit automakers was defeated at the behest of Senate Republicans in December 2008.
The moral hazard of the original Chrysler bailout showed up in subsequent actions by the automakers, as detailed in Chapter 4. The impetus to make more reliable, attractive, fuel-efficient cars seemed to have been forgotten until it was way too late. For many years, innovative designs and automotive technologies were the sole province of Japanese and German auto designers. Making ever less expensive cars became the province of the Koreans.
Meanwhile, the Big Three spent much of the intervening decades since the bailout—and millions upon millions of dollars—lobbying Congress. Rather than innovate the way other manufacturers did, they fought for exemptions from Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standards, or litigated against emission standards from states such as California.
As a car guy, I can say without hesitation that General Motors hasn't designed a dashboard that wasn't ugly as shit since the 1950s (the early 1960s Corvettes were the sole exception, but they were a special project). The biggest automotive accomplishment out of Detroit during recent decades was getting SUVs exempt from various car safety and fuel efficiency rules. Is it any wonder that Toyota has royally kicked GM's ass since then, bypassing the still-bloated manufacturer for the number one slot in auto sales in the United States? Toyota is now the world's biggest automaker. I am hard-pressed to name any nonfinancial American company that
deserves
bankruptcy more than GM.
T
here is yet another reason to be wary of broad government interventions : Vast amounts of money up for grabs have a tendency to corrupt anything they come near. The pork attached to the original Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) plan was a disgraceful showing. It was an embarrassing spectacle of business as usual from a Congress with the lowest approval rating of any political organ in America. To merely witness it made one rethink the wisdom of poll taxes, and reconsider one's belief in democracy.
BOOK: Bailout Nation
11.48Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

Other books

Slow Dollar by Margaret Maron
New World, New Love by Rosalind Laker
Diamond Girls by Wilson, Jacqueline
Facing the Light by Adèle Geras
Near a Thousand Tables by Felipe Fernandez-Armesto
IntheArmsofaLover by Madeleine Oh
A Barricade in Hell by Jaime Lee Moyer
Funland by Richard Laymon
The Price of Altruism by Oren Harman