Power Game (7 page)

Read Power Game Online

Authors: Hedrick Smith

BOOK: Power Game
13.6Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

In revolt, Congress vigorously asserted its authority and its independence from the White House and then armed itself for a prolonged seige against the executive branch. In reaction to Johnson’s escalation of the war in Vietnam without any congressional declaration of war, Congress in 1973 passed the War Powers Resolution requiring any president to obtain congressional approval for commitment of American forces to a combat zone for more than ninety days. Alarmed by Central Intelligence Agency operations such as attempts at assassinating foreign leaders, Congress asserted new oversight authority, requiring notice of all CIA covert operations. To check presidential authority further, Congress demanded that all executive branch agreements with other countries—those below the status of formal treaties—get Senate approval. All these restrictions hemmed in presidential power.

In reaction to the taint of Nixon’s corporate campaign slush funds, Congress voted for public financing of presidential elections. In reaction to its own budget conflict with President Nixon, Congress passed the Budget and Impoundment Control Act of 1974, to bar future presidents from refusing to spend what Congress voted. That law also set up a new Congressional budget process and established the Congressional
Budget Office (CBO) to produce independent analysis of the economy and budget; Congress no longer had to depend on administration economists.

That single change—an independent Congressional Budget Office—was crucial, and symptomatic. Such congressional power was unthinkable in the era of John Kennedy and Lyndon Johnson. When I arrived in Washington in 1962, Congress simply accepted the administration’s economic figures. Arguments were over policy, rarely over the facts. From a distance, the significance may be hard to appreciate. But when Congress got its own economic experts and facts, the executive branch was much more often thrown on the defensive.

“The creation of CBO was of fundamental importance in terms of the way power operates in Washington,” insisted Stuart Eizenstat, who felt its power as domestic policy chief in the Carter White House.

“One can trace from the time of the New Deal through the early and mid-parts of the Nixon Administration, a clear, gradual, perceptible increase in presidential power relative to the legislative branch,” Eizenstat pointed out. “The creation of CBO began to redress the balance of power. It did that via one fundamental way—it ended the president’s monopoly on information, on budget forecasts, on economic forecasts. The fact is that the CBO staff has been consistently more accurate on their economic forecasts, their deficit projections, than the executive branch has.

“What does that mean? It means that the president says, ‘Look, I think we’re in a four-and-one-half-percent growth year and therefore that leaves room for more spending’ or ‘that enables us to cut the budget’ or ‘that enables us to spend more on defense’ or, if you’re a Democratic president, more on domestic policy. And CBO says, ‘No, we think that growth is going to be three percent.’ And therefore you’ve just lost something on the order of $20 billion [in tax revenues for the budget].”
2

Beyond that, CBO can kill new proposals or force drastic revisions merely by giving realistic cost estimates. Eizenstat recalled that in 1977, Joseph Califano, then secretary of Health, Education and Welfare, proposed modest changes in welfare programs, introducing some new elements and offsetting their costs with efficiencies in existing programs. Overall, Califano reckoned the added cost at about $5 billion in 1978.

One morning after the legislation had gone to Congress, Eizenstat was struck by a newspaper headline:
CBO TO CARTER—WELFARE REFORM
$17
BILLION
. The CBO staff, then led by Alice Rivlin, a liberal
Democratic economist, had dismissed Califano’s efficiencies as largely fictional. It pegged the annual cost of Califano’s proposals—in full operation—at $17 billion.

“The second I saw that headline,” Eizenstat recalled, “I said, ‘Our program’s over. There’s no way the Congress is going to pass what they think is a $17 billion welfare-reform proposal.’ ”

The same sort of thing happened to Reagan. The CBO constantly challenged White House economic projections that were tilted to make Reagan’s budgets look better. On the 1987 budget, CBO accused the Reagan administration of understating what the Pentagon would spend by $15 billion. With the higher CBO figure, congressional Republicans as well as Democrats put a tighter squeeze on the Pentagon. It was a dramatic illustration of how the seemingly innocent capacity to make calculations changed the balance of power between the White House and Congress.

The CBO’s new clout epitomized the effort by Congress to build its own expertise on everything from farm programs to Star Wars, because members of Congress did not trust the executive branch to give them the straight story. Congress expanded the personal staffs of individual senators and House members and the committee staffs in both houses; it created the CBO, added to the research service of the Library of Congress, and expanded other support agencies. Overall, congressional staff jumped from about 11,500 to more than 24,000 between 1973 and 1985, as Congress armed itself to lay seige to the executive branch.
3

But simultaneously, the House of Representatives overturned its own power structure. Mainstream congressional Democrats had bridled for years at the seniority system and the power baronies it gave to conservative committee chairmen from the “Solid South.” The Democratic Study Group (DSG), the powerful informal caucus of House liberals, felt squeezed between the committee barons and a president whom they did not trust. According to Dick Conlon, the DSG’s executive director, the DSG set a strategy in late 1969 for breaking up the old baronies.

In 1971 and 1973, they pushed through changes in the rules of the House Democratic Caucus, establishing more democratic principles.
4
The reformers took powers from the old oligarchy and turned them over to the Democratic Caucus as a whole, and also to the speaker, secure in the knowledge that with Carl Albert as a weak speaker, they did not have to worry about that post. Then in early 1975, reinforced by seventy-five freshman Democrats elected in 1974, the reformers ousted three long-entrenched committee chairmen: Wright Patman of
the Banking Committee, F. Edward Hebert of Armed Services, and W. R. Poage of Agriculture.

Of course, the seniority system did not disappear entirely.
5
In 1986, North Carolina’s Jesse Helms won a seniority fight in the Senate. But the system in the House was dramatically altered by the 1974 upheavals. After that, no other power baron could dare to act as dictatorially as in the past. The spirit of ’74 flared again in 1985: Les Aspin, a Wisconsin Democrat, led a coalition of mostly younger members to overthrow Mel Price, the Armed Services Committee chairman. Then Aspin leaped over seven senior committee members to take the chairmanship himself. Aspin’s own power was challenged two years later. Although he managed to hang on, this challenge and counter challenge reminded all committee chairmen they could not afford to ignore rank-and-file members.

Even more significant for the long run, the House Democrats in 1974 had adopted “the subcommittee bill of rights” which decentralized power in the House, radically changing the way the power game would be played from then until now. In a stroke, it took power that had largely rested with the barons, the chairmen of the twenty-two House standing committees, and parceled out a healthy share of that power to 172 subcommittees. The number of subcommittees suddenly mushroomed in 1975, later to recede. But the more important change was the way things worked. In the old game, the power barons kept choice subcommittees for themselves and parceled out a few subcommittee chairs to allies, usually by seniority. Now, suddenly, junior Democrats, backbenchers, could seek reelection as subcommittee chairmen and then, as chairmen, they could hector the administration, bargain with high officials, push their pet ideas, or simply grab publicity. They could hire staff and run hearings. They had turf to protect and small subgovernments to manage. Many of them were aggressive and freewheeling, no longer under the thumb of full committee chairmen.

Even reformers such as Morris Udall, the veteran congressman from Arizona, sometimes groaned at what they had done. There were so many new subcommittee chairmen that Udall once joked to me that when he passed some junior Democrat whose name he’d forgotten, he would simply say, “Good morning, Mr. Chairman,” knowing that roughly half the time, he’d be right, because just about half of the House Democrats were chairs of committees or subcommittees. Power had sprawled that widely.

Less dramatically, but just as surely, the dispersal of power hit the
Senate, too. “We have proliferated the number of committees and subcommittees, the number of staff, the number of floor amendments, the number of cloture votes, the number of roll call votes, the number of fiscal processes,” asserted Indiana Republican Senator Dan Quayle, summing up a Senate study in late 1984. Actually, the subcommittee surge had ebbed by then, and the numbers had declined from peak levels in the mid-seventies. But still Quayle, like many others, was dismayed. “We have trivialized the matters with which we are concerned,” Quayle charged. “We use our processes more and more to emphasize small issues rather than large ones, and that is turning the Senate away from its historic function as the focus of national debate.”
6

It was more a matter of changing political style than mere numbers. Individual senators had become more aggressive about pursuing their own agendas, disrupting their own leaders. In late 1985, Senator Tom Eagleton, a three-term Democrat from Missouri, protested in exasperation that the Senate was suffering from “unbridled chaos.” He objected strenuously to independent-minded members launching so many filibusters—more in the last seventeen years than in the previous 170—and frequently blocking votes on legislation with endless amendments.
7
Quayle objected that one defense-funding bill was subjected to 103 amendments, fewer than ten of which he found “substantive.” In his folksy way, Senator David Pryor of Arkansas complained of the paralysis of the Senate. “Being in the Senate,” he told my colleague, Steve Roberts of
The New York Times
, “is like getting stuck in an airport and having all your flights canceled.”

In sum, proliferation of power in Congress, and loosening discipline, have made it far harder for any administration or any congressional leaders to pull together coalitions to pass major legislation. Votes have to be gathered up much more laboriously; it takes marathon bargaining. The White House cannot count on simply striking a deal with a small coterie or working out a tax compromise, say, with Wilbur Mills, who reigned for years as the lord of tax legislation from his throne as chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee. In the old Washington power game, when Mills gave his word, he could deliver his committee and that virtually assured passage in the House. But in the new Washington power game, committee majorities are far from automatic. A chairman such as Danny Rostenkowski (who now holds Mills’s seat) is influential, to be sure. But almost every member of Rostenkowski’s committee has to be won over individually, and each member’s pet provisions have to be accommodated. That takes months of one-by-one negotiating.

This situation has driven both Democratic and Republican administrations wild. I remember a small private dinner at the White House with President Carter in 1978. Eighteen of us were gathered around the table in the family quarters. Over coffee, President Carter talked about policy. I have a vivid memory of his acute frustration over the entangling ways of Congress. His top priority, his energy legislation, he told us, had to pass through twenty-two different congressional committees and subcommittees. The process had become an impossible legislative steeplechase.

Viewing the new power game from a different angle, Tommy Boggs, a highly successful lobbyist, grinned and said to me, “The Washington establishment has been blown wide open.”
8

Crowds Kill the Old Coziness

The new power game has not only multiplied the centers and circles of power, but it has led to a more piecemeal, jumbled, adversarial brand of politics. The faster tempo, the crowded calendar, and the growth of everything have made members of Congress less familiar to each other and, some argue, less accustomed to the comity and give-and-take that make government work more easily.

“I came here in ’61, the last congressman sworn in by Sam Rayburn,” recalled Morris Udall, the slender, likable Arizonan who ran second for the Democratic presidential nomination in 1976. “This used to be a small town when I got here. I knew the names of the administrative assistants and key assistants for most of the members. You knew their wives and some of the children. But it’s exploded. Now at noon, I’m told, the population on Capitol Hill is twenty-five thousand, and you don’t know everybody anymore. You’re always running into people you’ve never met.”
9

It sounds like the nostalgia of old-timers everywhere, except that this time the facts support Udall’s memories of dramatic change. Before the jet airplane made travel home quick and easy, Udall contended, members of Congress had more time to talk about policy, time to socialize, time to get to know each other. That familiarity oiled the wheels of compromise and made government workable.

“It used to be that my brother, who held the seat before I did, would drive his car or take a train, which meant that if you were from west of the Mississippi, you were stuck in Washington for five, six months while the session ground on,” Mo explained (he is Mo to everyone). “You’d have a party and invite all your committee members and their
wives, or the Eighty-seventh Congress Club would have an annual get-together. But now, I would venture that the average member does not know, could not identify half of his colleagues.”

The new strangeness, Mo lamented, “tends to provoke confrontation and all the things you have in an impersonal institution.” He was reminded of frictions he had seen elsewhere. “I practiced law in Tucson, and I knew every lawyer in town, knew their families. You knew whose word was good. You knew a few guys you couldn’t trust. And the courtroom demeanor was always very friendly. I went to Chicago once to extradite somebody when I was the prosecuting attorney, and the opposing lawyers were treated like thieves and crooks. Unpleasant. And you find that tendency here. You find that people are suspicious of each other.”

Other books

The Stars of San Cecilio by Susan Barrie
The Two Devils by David B. Riley
Bones of a Witch by Dana Donovan
Mira by Leighann Phoenix
The Mystery at the Dog Show by Gertrude Chandler Warner
The Killer II by Jack Elgos
Refugee: Force Heretic II by Sean Williams