Strange Rebels: 1979 and the Birth of the 21st Century (60 page)

Read Strange Rebels: 1979 and the Birth of the 21st Century Online

Authors: Christian Caryl

Tags: #History, #Revolutionary, #Modern, #20th Century, #Political Science, #International Relations, #General, #World, #Political Ideologies

BOOK: Strange Rebels: 1979 and the Birth of the 21st Century
4.97Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

It is easy to look askance at the enemies of reform from the vantage point of today, when the extraordinary power and prosperity that Deng’s course has brought to China are manifest. But this outcome was not quite so clear to observers in the 1980s. The transfiguration of the economy brought unheralded opportunities, but it also produced dislocation, turmoil, and dizzying social change. While some sectors of the economy boomed, others collapsed, requiring huge injections of investment from the state in order to prevent mass layoffs; unemployment went up sharply in some parts of the country nonetheless. The rising prosperity of the industrial areas along the coasts attracted huge numbers of job-seeking immigrants from the interior, setting off what would ultimately become the largest peacetime migration in history. The rise of a new class of business owners and managers transformed the social hierarchy. The Communist Party was at first unsure whether to welcome them into its ranks or to hold them at arm’s length.

In keeping with the demands of a new economy, the country’s legal system had to be completely reengineered. Growing numbers of foreigners appeared on the streets, and knowledge of the outside world proliferated. Blue and gray Mao suits gave way to a diverse global wardrobe. Western fast food changed eating habits. Until the end of the 1970s, the average Chinese had dreamed of the Four Big Things: a sewing machine, a bicycle, a wristwatch, and a radio. In the 1980s, the list went upmarket. Now the aspirational possessions were a refrigerator, a TV set, a rice cooker, and a washing machine.

The career of Hu Yaobang offers a case study in the challenges that China faced when it came to reconciling its peculiar mix of economic liberalization and political immobility. Hu—the man who had brought up the sensitive issue of agricultural reform at the 1978 Central Party Work Conference, like a “finger pushing through a paper window”—enjoyed a steep ascent in the early years of the reform period. He was among the most determined supporters of economic reform. As the Communist Party organization chief in the late 1970s, he had also pushed aggressively for the rehabilitation of countless victims of the Cultural Revolution. It was an effort that had earned him not only plenty of moral credibility but also a bank vault’s worth of valuable political capital that he could draw upon in the years to come.

In 1980, thanks to Deng’s patronage, Hu became general secretary of the party and also attained membership in the Politburo Standing Committee, the small
group of men who effectively ran China. Hu’s record as an arch-reformer cemented his status as Deng’s most important deputy. Hu pushed hard for economic liberalization and personally oversaw measures that gave industrial enterprises more autonomy and allowed them to retain more profits for themselves. He also presided over agricultural reforms that extended the term farmers were allowed to rent land from the state, thus reinforcing the principle of private initiative. His term also saw an expansion of the Special Economic Zones to encompass even greater areas along the coast.

But Hu’s success also contained the seeds of his own destruction. His mercurial personality alienated Deng and created friction with fellow reformer Zhao Ziyang. In the mid-1980s, meanwhile, the release of entrepreneurial energies meant that the economy began to overheat. The gradual abolition of price controls on certain goods—the inevitable consequence of the shift away from a centrally planned economy—meant that inflation soared. Inequality deepened. Officials as well as members of the new business class often proved unwilling to wait for wealth, and corruption rose correspondingly. And Hu’s insistence on the need for political reform to accompany economic restructuring went decidedly too far for a Communist Party leadership that was growing nervous about its hold on power in a tumultuous period of change. In 1987 he was forced to resign his post as general secretary of the party and retired, disappearing into the limbo that invariably envelops all Chinese leaders who fall into official disfavor.

Then came the news, in April 1989, that Hu had died of a heart attack. The party leadership initially balked at affording him a state funeral but soon relented—perhaps recalling the Tiananmen Incident of 1976, when similar reluctance to acknowledge the death of Zhou Enlai had prompted popular demonstrations against the Maoists. If so, those fears proved legitimate. In 1989, just as had been the case with Zhou, the perception of a posthumous party snub angered Hu’s supporters, and soon groups of students were using his death as a rallying point for protests against corruption and rising inflation. The students believed that the best way to remedy such social ills was to curb the power of the party by establishing more democratic institutions (though the protesters were often vague about how this was to be accomplished in practice).

The party, which had rather different ideas on this score, harshly condemned the protests, which prompted them to spread beyond Beijing to dozens of other cities around China. In some places, workers joined the students, setting off alarm bells in the minds of party leaders who were especially sensitive to the ideological
threat posed by anti-Communist proletarians. Some of the students camped out on Tiananmen Square started a hunger strike to press their demands for more democracy. Various party stalwarts paid visits to the students, warning them to desist. The visitors included, toward the end, Zhao Ziyang himself, who pleaded with them to put an end to the protests. Mikhail Gorbachev came to Beijing, and his example inflamed the malcontents: why couldn’t China implement its own brand of perestroika?

How it all ended is known. In the early hours of June 4, 1989, the Communist Party declared martial law and sent in the troops. We may never know the precise casualties, but it seems safe to say that hundreds of people were killed in central Beijing that day. Even more obscure is the outcome in dozens of other Chinese cities where similar protests were suppressed at the same time. The chairman of the Central Military Commission, the man who issued the command for the crackdown, was none other than Deng Xiaoping. In 1977 those who yearned for an end to Maoist turmoil had greeted Deng’s return to power by hanging up small bottles over Beijing’s streets, a play on his name (
xiaoping
can mean “small bottle”). In 1989 students confined to their dormitory buildings smashed bottles as an expression of their anger and frustration.
11

Deng was not shy about giving the order. Later, in an address to People’s Liberation Army troops, he hailed the party’s actions in the most uncompromising terms:

            
We . . . face a rebellious clique and a large number of the dregs of society, who want to topple our country and overthrow our party. This is the essence of the problem. . . . They have two main slogans: One is to topple the Communist Party, and the other is to overthrow the socialist system. Their goal is to establish a totally Western-dependent bourgeois republic. The people want to combat corruption. This, of course, we accept. We should also take the so-called anticorruption slogans raised by people with ulterior motives as good advice and accept them accordingly. Of course, these slogans are just a front: The heart of these slogans is to topple the Communist Party and overthrow the socialist system.
12

Rarely has Deng revealed his fundamental assumptions as clearly as he did in this passage. He had not spent his adult life anchoring Communist Party rule to see it dismantled by student radicals. At the same time, however, Deng moved to ensure that the course of economic reform would continue. This reassurance was crucial.

Notably, Deng never repeated his 1978 flirtations with the prodemocracy movement. He named his program “socialism with Chinese characteristics,” and he seemed quite sincere in this. It all depends, perhaps, on one’s definition of
socialism
. For Deng, the word seemed to mean, above all, a system that could unify a notoriously fractious country; it did not refer to Maoist-style egalitarianism, the radical leveling of all differences. To the end of his life, Deng adamantly insisted that he opposed “capitalism.” And when the liberals began to express their longing for more democracy in the late 1980s, Deng issued a pitiless rejection. Some of his closest associates were brutally scapegoated, stripped of their posts and packed off into political neverland. Zhao Ziyang, the only Politburo member to vote against a military solution to the student protests, and who had visited the students in Tiananmen Square shortly before the crackdown, was stripped of his posts and relegated to house arrest.

The conservatives, whose influence had been rising even before Tiananmen, set out to brake China’s rush to the market. They lowered growth targets, tightened financial controls, and pushed for greater budget discipline. They even announced a moratorium on the construction of high-end office buildings and hotels. At a party conference in late 1989, Premier Li Peng declared that party controls over all matters ideological would be intensified.
13
The SEZs, again, were at the forefront of the debate. The new emphasis on “patriotic education” and the ban on anything that smacked of “bourgeois liberalization” did not square well with the cosmopolitan allure of a place like Shenzhen. For a time, Deng was willing to concede ground to them. But he was not willing to backtrack completely.

Chen Yun seemed to have won the argument. He had always regarded the zones as “birdcages,” places where the rapacious spirit of capitalism could be exploited even as it was kept in safe quarantine. (It was Chen who had argued, when the first special zones were established, that “you have to be careful about opening the window—the flies and the mosquitoes will come in.”) His defense of planning and his critique of market mechanisms dominated the public discussion. The conservatives held sway over the media. Some of Deng’s key allies deserted him. This time, it seemed, Deng had exhausted his political capital. He was already in semiretirement. Another comeback appeared improbable.
14

But then, in the winter of 1992, Deng announced that he intended to set off on a vacation in the sunny South. His special train stopped first in Shanghai, Chen Yun’s hometown. It was Chen’s memories of the 1920s and 1930s, when Shanghai’s economy was dominated by the foreign companies that retained imperial-era
concessions there, that made him a staunch opponent of so-called comprador capitalism. In 1979 there had been talk of including Shanghai in the original group of Special Economic Zones, but Chen had quashed the idea. By the late 1980s, senior party officials were discussing plans to transform the Pudong district of Shanghai into a special zone designed to attract financial companies, alluding to the city’s prewar role as China’s banking center (a function that had since been assumed by Hong Kong). Chen continued to resist. But on his 1992 visit, Deng pressed the idea again, arguing that improved conditions for foreign banks could help to push economic development. His arguments were largely ignored by the national media—evidence, perhaps, that some in the party were already anticipating his retirement from the scene. If such expectations existed, they were soon to prove premature.

Deng’s train then pressed on to Guangdong Province. In Shenzhen he met with a rousing welcome from local party officials, who understood, quite accurately, that their own political fortunes were intimately connected with his. Deng toured factories and met with their workers, who gave him glowing accounts of the improved living standards and chances for mobility that Shenzhen offered. Deng viewed the zone’s first skyscrapers and inspected what had become, by now, its exemplary roads and port facilities. Shenzhen was producing goods to market around the world. It was also home to the first stock exchange in the People’s Republic of China, a remarkable sign of the spread of market norms. By this time, Hong Kong investors were employing 3 million mainland workers in the zone—three times more than in Hong Kong itself.
15
The vast majority of these workers came from somewhere else in China, extraordinary evidence of social mobility in a country that had, for decades, tied people to their places of birth. As evidence of this shift, most Shenzheners spoke Mandarin, the national version of Chinese, unlike most Guangdong natives, who speak the local dialect of Cantonese.

There were many problems, too—precisely the issues that had made Shenzhen and the other SEZs targets of the opposition to reform. There were stories of drug use, prostitution, and widespread corruption. The fifty-mile fence between Shenzhen and the rest of the mainland served to prevent the capitalist mind-set from infecting China as a whole.
16

But this was not what Deng chose to dwell upon during his visit. In speech after speech, he drew attention to the achievements of Shenzhen and the extraordinary speed of its development. At one point he recalled an early visit to the region: “I came to Guangdong in 1984. At that point, rural reform had been going for a few years, urban reform was just starting, and the special zones were taking their first
steps. Eight years have gone by and I would never have believed that on this visit I would find that Shenzhen and Zhuhai special zones had developed so fast. Having seen it, my confidence has increased.”
17

At first Deng’s speeches received coverage only from the Guangdong media, which celebrated his support for the province’s success. Guangdongers knew that Deng had played a crucial role in giving provincial government relative freedom from Beijing’s interference to push ahead with the economic experiments that had now borne such spectacular fruit. But the national media remained silent. Gradually, however, Deng’s sympathizers gained traction. It was only several weeks after his trip that most Chinese began to learn of Deng’s pilgrimage to Guangdong and to hear for themselves his forceful arguments in favor of continued opening to the world. The images of Shenzhen’s soaring towers and turbocharged factories resolved the hesitations of many party members who had been wondering whether the march toward the market was a good idea. Deng’s 1992 trip—which came to be known as the
nanxun
, the “Southern Tour”—galvanized the economic reformers and enabled them to gain a crucial edge over their opponents. It also dramatized the extent to which the Special Economic Zones had become the frontier of China’s market experiment. The Chinese never looked back.

Other books

Capitol Murder by Phillip Margolin
Charlene Sands by Lily Gets Her Man
Glue by Irvine Welsh
Sins of the Angels by Linda Poitevin
World’s End by Joan D. Vinge
Encompassing Reality by Richard Lord
The Geneva Project - Truth by Christina Benjamin
Magician Interrupted by S. V. Brown